Academia.eduAcademia.edu

Outline

The Evolution of Reputation-Based Cooperation in Regular Networks

https://doi.org/10.3390/G8010008

Abstract

Despite recent advances in reputation technologies, it is not clear how reputation systems can affect human cooperation in social networks. Although it is known that two of the major mechanisms in the evolution of cooperation are spatial selection and reputation-based reciprocity, theoretical study of the interplay between both mechanisms remains almost uncharted. Here, we present a new individual-based model for the evolution of reciprocal cooperation between reputation and networks. We comparatively analyze four of the leading moral assessment rules—shunning, image scoring, stern judging, and simple standing—and base the model on the giving game in regular networks for Cooperators, Defectors, and Discriminators. Discriminators rely on a proper moral assessment rule. By using individual-based models, we show that the four assessment rules are differently characterized in terms of how cooperation evolves, depending on the benefit-to-cost ratio, the network-node degree, and the observation and error conditions. Our findings show that the most tolerant rule—simple standing—is the most robust among the four assessment rules in promoting cooperation in regular networks.

References (75)

  1. Yamagishi, T.; Yoshikai, N. Towards trustable information society. J. Inst. Electron. Inf. Commun. Eng. 2005, 88, 54-56.
  2. Milinski, M. Reputation, a universal currency for human social interactions. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci. 2016, 371, 20150100. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  3. Sugden, R. The Economics of Rights, Cooperation and Welfare; Blackwell: Oxford, UK, 1986.
  4. Wedekind, C.; Milinski, M. Cooperation through image scoring in humans. Science 2000, 288, 850-852. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  5. Wedekind, C.; Braithwaite, V.A. The long-term benefits of human generosity in indirect reciprocity. Curr. Biol. 2002, 12, 1012-1015. [CrossRef]
  6. Sommerfeld, R.D.; Krambeck, H.-J.; Semmann, D.; Milinski, M. Gossip as an alternative for direct observation in games of indirect reciprocity. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2007, 104, 17435-17440. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  7. Nowak, M.A.; Sigmund, K. Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature 2005, 437, 1291-1298. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  8. Ohtsuki, H.; Iwasa, Y. How should we define goodness?-Reputation dynamics in indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 2004, 231, 107-120. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  9. Ohtsuki, H.; Iwasa, Y. The leading eight: Social norms that can maintain cooperation by indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 2006, 239, 435-444. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  10. Brandt, H.; Sigmund, K. The logic of reprobation: Action and assessment rules in indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 2004, 231, 475-486. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  11. Nowak, M.A.; May, R.M. Evolutionary games and spatial chaos. Nature 1992, 359, 826-829. [CrossRef]
  12. Santos, F.C.; Pacheco, J.M. Scale-free networks provide a unifying framework for the emergence of cooperation. Phys. Rev. Lett. 2005, 95, 098104. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  13. Nowak, M.A.; Tarnita, C.E.; Antal, T. Evolutionary dynamics in structured populations. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci. 2010, 365, 19-30. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  14. Wang, Z.; Kokubo, S.; Tanimoto, J.; Fukuda, E.; Shigaki, K. Insight into the so-called spatial reciprocity. Phys. Rev. E 2013, 88, 042145. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  15. Lindgren, K.; Nordahl, M.G. Evolutionary dynamics of spatial games. Physica D 1994, 75, 292-309. [CrossRef]
  16. Nakamaru, M.; Matsuda, H.; Iwasa, Y. The evolution of cooperation in a lattice-structured population. J. Theor. Biol. 1996, 184, 65-81. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  17. Brauchli, K.; Killingback, T.; Doebeli, M. Evolution of cooperation in spatially structured populations. J. Theor. Biol. 1999, 200, 405-417. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  18. Pacheco, J.M.; Traulsen, A.; Ohtsuki, H.; Nowak, M.A. Repeated games and direct reciprocity under active linking. J. Theor. Biol. 2008, 250, 723-731. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  19. Sekiguchi, T.; Nakamaru, M. Effect of the presence of empty sites on the evolution of cooperation by costly punishment in spatial games. J. Theor. Boil. 2009, 256, 297-304. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  20. Helbing, D.; Szolnoki, A.; Perc, M.; Szabó, G. Evolutionary establishment of moral and double moral standards through spatial interactions. PLoS Comput. Biol. 2010, 6, e1000758. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  21. Szolnoki, A.; Perc, M. Reward and cooperation in the spatial public goods game. EPL Europhys. Lett. 2010, 92, 38003. [CrossRef]
  22. Van Veelen, M.; García, J.; Rand, D.G.; Nowak, M.A. Direct reciprocity in structured populations. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2012, 109, 9929-9934. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  23. Liu, Y.; Chen, X.; Zhang, L.; Wang, L.; Perc, M. Win-stay-lose-learn promotes cooperation in the spatial prisoner's dilemma game. PLoS ONE 2012, 7, e30689. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  24. Szolnoki, A.; Perc, M. Evolution of extortion in structured populations. Phys. Rev. E 2014, 89, 022804. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  25. Nowak, M.A.; Roch, S. Upstream reciprocity and the evolution of gratitude. Proc. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci. 2007, 274, 605-610. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  26. Iwagami, A.; Masuda, N. Upstream reciprocity in heterogeneous networks. J. Theor. Biol. 2010, 265, 297-305. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  27. Van Doorn, G.S.; Taborsky, M. The evolution of generalized reciprocity on social interaction networks. Evolution 2012, 66, 651-664. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  28. Brandt, H.; Ohtsuki, H.; Iwasa, Y.; Sigmund, K. A survey of indirect reciprocity. In Mathematics for Ecology and Environmental Sciences; Takeuchi, Y., Iwasa, Y., Sato, K., Eds.; Springer: Berlin, Germany, 2007; pp. 21-49.
  29. Wang, Z.; Wang, L.; Yin, Z.-Y.; Xia, C.-Y. Inferring reputation promotes the evolution of cooperation in spatial social dilemma games. PLoS ONE 2012, 7, e40218. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  30. Chen, M.H.; Wang, L.; Sun, S.W.; Wang, J.; Xia, C.Y. Evolution of cooperation in the spatial public goods game with adaptive reputation assortment. Phys. Lett. A 2016, 380, 40-47. [CrossRef]
  31. Brandt, H.; Hauert, C.; Sigmund, K. Punishment and reputation in spatial public goods games. Proc. R. Soc. B 2003, 270, 1099-1104. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  32. Fu, F.; Hauert, C.; Nowak, M.A.; Wang, L. Reputation-based partner choice promotes cooperation in social networks. Phys. Rev. E 2008, 78, 026117. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  33. Sylwester, K.; Roberts, G. Reputation-based partner choice is an effective alternative to indirect reciprocity in solving social dilemmas. Evol. Hum. Behav. 2013, 34, 201-206. [CrossRef]
  34. Chen, X.; Schick, A.; Doebeli, M.; Blachford, A.; Wang, L. Reputation-based conditional interaction supports cooperation in well-mixed prisoner's dilemmas. PLoS ONE 2012, 7, e36260. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  35. Cong, R.; Wu, B.; Qiu, Y.; Wang, L. Evolution of cooperation driven by reputation-based migration. PLoS ONE 2012, 7, e35776. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  36. Cuesta, J.A.; Gracia-Lázaro, C.; Ferrer, A.; Moreno, Y.; Sánchez, A. Reputation drives cooperative behaviour and network formation in human groups. Sci. Rep. 2015, 5, 7843. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  37. Gallo, E.; Yan, C. The effects of reputational and social knowledge on cooperation. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2015, 112, 3647-3652. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  38. Rockenbach, B.; Milinski, M. The efficient interaction of indirect reciprocity and costly punishment. Nature 2006, 444, 718-723. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  39. Bednarik, P.; Fehl, K.; Semmann, D. Costs for switching partners reduce network dynamics but not cooperative behaviour. Proc. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci. 2014, 281, 20141661. [CrossRef]
  40. Nowak, M.A.; Sigmund, K. Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring. Nature 1998, 282, 462-466.
  41. Swakman, V.; Molleman, L.; Ule, A.; Egas, M. Reputation-based cooperation: Empirical evidence for behavioral strategies. Evol. Hum. Behav. 2016, 37, 230-235. [CrossRef]
  42. Milinski, M.; Semmann, D.; Bakker, T.C.M.; Krambeck, H.J. Cooperation through indirect reciprocity: Image scoring or standing strategy? Proc. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci. 2001, 268, 2495-2501. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  43. Antonioni, A.; Cacault, M.P.; Lalive, R.; Tomassini, M. Know thy neighbor: Costly information can hurt cooperation in dynamic networks. PLoS ONE 2014, 9, e110788. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  44. Suzuki, S.; Kimura, H. Indirect reciprocity is sensitive to costs of information transfer. Sci. Rep. 2013, 3, 1435. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  45. Sasaki, T.; Okada, I.; Nakai, Y. Indirect reciprocity can overcome free-rider problems on costly moral assessment. Biol. Lett. 2016, 12, 20160341. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  46. Leimar, O.; Hammerstein, P. Evolution of cooperation through indirect reciprocity. Proc. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci. 2001, 268, 745-753. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  47. Panchanathan, K.; Boyd, R. A tale of two defectors: The importance of standing for evolution of indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 2003, 224, 115-126. [CrossRef]
  48. Kandori, M. Social norms and community enforcement. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1992, 59, 63-80. [CrossRef]
  49. Pacheco, J.M.; Santos, F.C.; Chalub, F.A.C. Stern-judging: A simple, successful norm which promotes cooperation under indirect reciprocity. PLoS Comput. Biol. 2006, 2, e178. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  50. Takahashi, N.; Mashima, R. The importance of subjectivity in perceptual errors on the emergence of indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 2006, 243, 418-436. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  51. Suzuki, T.; Kobayashi, T. Effect of tolerance of reputation-making norms on corporation in social exchanges: An evolutionary simulation on social networks. Sociol. Theory Methods 2011, 26, 31-50.
  52. Nakai, Y.; Muto, M. Emergence and collapse of peace with friend selection strategies. J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simul. 2008, 11, 6.
  53. Uchida, S. Effect of private information on indirect reciprocity. Phys. Rev. E 2010, 82, 036111. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  54. Sigmund, K. The Calculus of Selfishness; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2010.
  55. Takahashi, N.; Mashima, R. The Emergence of Indirect Reciprocity: Is the Standing Strategy the Answer? COE Working Paper 29; Hokkaido University: Hokkaido, Japan, 2003; Available online: http://lynx.let.hokudai. ac.jp/COE21/workingpaper/ (accessed on 14 September 2016).
  56. Hofbauer, J.; Sigmund, K. Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1998.
  57. Ohtsuki, H.; Iwasa, Y. Global analyses of evolutionary dynamics and exhaustive search for social norms that maintain cooperation by reputation. J. Theor. Biol. 2007, 244, 518-531. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  58. Santos, F.P.; Santos, F.C.; Pacheco, J.M. Social Norms of Cooperation in Small-Scale Societies. PLoS Comput. Biol. 2016, 12, e1004709. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  59. Sigmund, K. Moral assessment in indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 2012, 299, 25-30. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  60. Oishi, K.; Shimada, T.; Ito, N. Group formation through indirect reciprocity. Phys. Rev. E 2013, 87, 030801. [CrossRef]
  61. Pollock, G.B.; Dugatkin, L.A. Reciprocity and the evolution of reputation. J. Theor. Biol. 1992, 159, 25-37.
  62. Ohtsuki, H.; Iwasa, Y.; Nowak, M.A. Indirect reciprocity provides only a narrow margin of efficiency for costly punishment. Nature 2009, 457, 79-82. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  63. Wu, J.; Balliet, D.; Van Lange, P.A. Gossip versus punishment: The efficiency of reputation to promote and maintain cooperation. Sci. Rep. 2016, 6, 23919. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  64. Yamagishi, T. The provision of a sanctioning system as a public good. J. Personal. Soc. Psychol. 1986, 51, 110-116. [CrossRef]
  65. Sigmund, K.; de Silva, H.; Traulsen, A.; Hauert, C. Social learning promotes institutions for governing the commons. Nature 2010, 466, 861-863. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  66. Sasaki, T.; Okada, I.; Uchida, S.; Chen, X. Commitment to cooperation and peer punishment: Its evolution. Games 2015, 6, 574-587. [CrossRef]
  67. Han, T.A.; Lenaerts, T. A synergy of costly punishment and commitment in cooperation dilemmas. Adapt. Behav. 2016. [CrossRef]
  68. Szolnoki, A.; Szabó, G.; Czakó, L. Competition of individual and institutional punishments in spatial public goods games. Phys. Rev. E 2011, 84, 046106. [CrossRef] [PubMed] Games 2017, 8, 8 16 of 16
  69. Ichinose, G.; Tenguishi, Y.; Tanizawa, T. Robustness of cooperation on scale-free networks under continuous topological change. Phys. Rev. E 2013, 88, 052808. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  70. Ishida, Y.; Yamamoto, H.; Okada, I.; Ota, T. Robustness and vulnerability of cooperation: Emergence on network structures. Comput. Softw. 2007, 24, 70-80.
  71. Nakamaru, M.; Kawata, M. Evolution of rumors that discriminate lying defectors. Evol. Ecol. Res. 2004, 6, 261-283.
  72. Ghang, W.; Nowak, M.A. Indirect reciprocity with optional interactions. J. Theor. Biol. 2015, 365, 1-11. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  73. Számadó, S.; Szalai, F.; Scheuring, I. Deception undermines the stability of cooperation in games of indirect reciprocity. PLoS ONE 2016, 11, e0147623. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  74. Antonioni, A.; Sánchez, A.; Tomassini, M. Cooperation survives and cheating pays in a dynamic network structure with unreliable reputation. Sci. Rep. 2016, 6, 27160. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  75. Seki, M.; Nakamaru, M. Model for gossip-mediated evolution of altruism with various types of false information by speakers and assessment by listeners. J. Theor. Biol. 2016, 407, 90-105. [CrossRef] [PubMed]