Abstract
In a laboratory experiment, we create relationships between pairs of anonymous subjects through a Prisoners' dilemma game. Thereafter the same subjects play a private values (sealed-bid double auction) bargaining game with or without communication. Communication substantially increases bargaining efficiency among subjects who cooperated in the Prisoners' dilemma, but has no significant effect on bargaining outcomes when one subject defected. Subjects who cooperated in the Prisoners' dilemma bid more aggressively if their opponent defected. Cooperators also lie more about their valuations when their opponent defected: Compared to the case of mutual cooperation, the cooperators' rate of honest revelation decreases from 64% to 6% and the rate of outright deception increases from 7% to 53%. Our results provide qualitatively new evidence that many people are strong reciprocators: They are willing to bear private costs in order to reward good behavior and punish bad behavior, even when the rewards and punishments are unobservable.
References (31)
- Ben-Ami, S. Quel Avenir Pour Israël? Paris: Presses Universitaires de France, 2001.
- Brandts, J., and Charness, G. (2003): "Truth or Consequences: An Experiment." Management Science 49, 116-130.
- Camerer, C.F. (2003): Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
- Charness, G., Dufwenberg, M. (2006): "Promises and Partnership." Econometrica 74, 1579- 1601.
- Chartrand, T.L. and Bargh, J.A. (1999): "The Chameleon Effect: The Perception-Behavior Link and Social Interaction," Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 76, 893-910.
- Chatterjee K. and Samuelson W. (1983): "Bargaining Under Incomplete Information". Operations Research 31, 835-851.
- Crawford, V. (1997): "Theory and Experiment in the Analysis of Strategic Interactions," in
- Kreps, D. and Wallis, K. (eds.), Advances in Economic Theory, Seventh World Congress, volume 1, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
- Crawford, V. (1998): "A Survey of Experiments on Communication via Cheap Talk." Journal of Economic Theory 78, 286-298.
- Ellingsen, T. and Johannesson, M. (2004): "Promises, Threats and Fairness." Economic Journal 114, 397-420.
- Farrell, J. and Gibbons, R. (1989): "Cheap Talk Can Matter in Bargaining," Journal of Economic Theory 48, 221-237.
- Fehr, E. and Fischbacher, U. (2003): "The Nature of Human Altruism," Nature 425, 785-791.
- Fehr, E. and Fischbacher, U., and Gächter, S. (2002): "Strong Reciprocity, Human Cooperation, and the Enforcement of Social Norms," Human Nature 13, 1-25.
- Fehr, E. and Fischbacher, U., and Kosfeld, M. (2005): Neuroeconomic Foundations of Trust and Social Preferences, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 95, 346-351.
- Frank, R.H. (1987): "If Homo Economicus Could Choose His Own Utility Function, Would He Want One With a Conscience?" American Economic Review 77, 593-604.
- Frank, R.H. (1988): Passions within Reason. New York: W.W. Norton.
- Gneezy, U. (2005): "Deception: The Role of Consequences." American Economic Review 95, pp. 384-394.
- Gross Stein, J. (Ed.), (1989): Getting to the Table: The Processes of International Prenegotiation. Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
- Hoffman, E. and Spitzer, M. (1982): "The Coase Theorem: Some Experimental Tests," Journal of Law and Economics 25, 73-98.
- Hurkens, S. and Kartik, N. (2006): "(When) Would I Lie to You? Comment on "Deception: The Role of Consequences." Mimeo.
- Mohlin, E. and Johannesson, M. (2006): "Communication: Content or Relationship?" Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, forthcoming.
- Montville, J. (1993): "The Healing Function in Political Conflict Resolution." In: Sandole, D. and van der Merwe, H. (Eds.). Conflict Resolution Theory and Practice. Manchester: Manchester University Press.
- Myerson, R. and Satterthwaite, M. (1983): "Pre-play Communication in Two-person Sealed- Bid Double Auctions." Journal of Economic Theory 28, 265-281.
- Radner, R. and Schotter, A. (1989): "The Sealed-bid Mechanism: An Experimental Study," Journal of Economic Theory 48, 179-220.
- Sally, D. (1995): "Conversation and Cooperation in Social Dilemmas: A Meta-Analysis of Experiments from 1958-1992," Rationality and Society 7, 58-92.
- Saunders, H. (1985): "We Need a Larger Theory of Negotiation: The Importance of Pre- Negotiating Phases," Negotiation Journal 1(3), 249-262.
- Terris, W. and Jones, J. (1982): "Psychological Factors Related to Employee Theft in the Convenience Store Industry," Psychological Reports 51, 1219-1238.
- Tyler, J.M., Feldman, R.S., and Reichert, A. (2006): "The Price of Deceptive Behavior: Disliking and Lying to People Who Lie to Us," Journal of Experimental and Social Psychology 42, 69-77.
- Valley, K. L., Neale, M. A. and Mannix, F. A. (1995): "Friends, Lovers, Colleagues, Strangers: The Effects of Relationships on the Process and Outcome of Dyadic Negotiations." in Bies, R. J., Lewicki, R and Sheppard, B. (eds.). Research on Negotiation in Organizations. Greenwich, CN: JAI Press.
- Valley, K.L., Thompson, L., Gibbons, R., and Bazerman, M.H. (2002): "How Communication Improves Efficiency in Bargaining Games," Games and Economic Behavior 38, 127-155.
- Zartman, I.W. "Prenegotiation: Phases and Functions." International Journal, 1989, 44(2): 237-253.