Cognitive Hierarchies in Extensive Form Games
2022
Abstract
The cognitive hierarchy (CH) approach posits that players in a game are heterogeneous with respect to levels of strategic sophistication. A level-k player believes all other players in the game have lower levels of sophistication distributed from 0 to k 1, and these beliefs correspond to the truncated distribution of a “true” distribution of levels. We extend the CH framework to extensive form games, where these initial beliefs over lower levels are updated as the history of play in the game unfolds, providing information to players about other players’ levels of sophistication. For a class of centipede games with a linearly increasing pie, we fully characterize the dynamic CH solution and show that it leads to the game terminating earlier than in the static CH solution for the centipede game in reduced normal form. JEL Classification Numbers: C72
References (53)
- Alaoui, L. and A. Penta (2016): "Endogenous depth of reasoning," The Review of Economic Studies, 83, 1297-1333.
- ---(2018): "Cost-benefit analysis in reasoning," Working Paper.
- Aumann, R. (1988): "Preliminary notes on integrating irrationality into game theory," in International Conference on Economic Theories of Politics, Haifa.
- Aumann, R. J. (1992): "Irrationality in game theory," Economic analysis of markets and games, 214-227.
- Banks, J. S. (1985): "Sophisticated voting outcomes and agenda control," Social Choice and Welfare, 1, 295-306.
- Binmore, K. (1987): "Modeling rational players: Part I," Economics & Philosophy, 3, 179-214.
- ---(1988): "Modeling rational players: Part II," Economics & Philosophy, 4, 9-55.
- Bohren, J. A. (2016): "Informational herding with model misspecification," Journal of Economic Theory, 163, 222-247.
- Bornstein, G., T. Kugler, and A. Ziegelmeyer (2004): "Individual and group de- cisions in the centipede game: Are groups more "rational" players?" Journal of Experi- mental Social Psychology, 40, 599-605.
- Brandts, J. and G. Charness (2011): "The strategy versus the direct-response method: a first survey of experimental comparisons," Experimental Economics, 14, 375-398.
- Cai, H. and J. T.-Y. Wang (2006): "Overcommunication in strategic information trans- mission games," Games and Economic Behavior, 56, 7-36.
- Camerer, C. F. (2003): Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction, Princeton university press.
- Camerer, C. F., T.-H. Ho, and J.-K. Chong (2004): "A cognitive hierarchy model of games," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 861-898.
- Chamley, C. and D. Gale (1994): "Information revelation and strategic delay in a model of investment," Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 1065-1085.
- Choi, S., D. Gale, and S. Kariv (2008): "Sequential equilibrium in monotone games: A analysis of experimental data," Journal of Economic Theory, 143, 302-330.
- Costa-Gomes, M., V. P. Crawford, and B. Broseta (2001): "Cognition and behav- ior in normal-form games: An experimental study," Econometrica, 69, 1193-1235.
- Costa-Gomes, M. A. and V. P. Crawford (2006): "Cognition and behavior in two- person guessing games: An experimental study," American economic review, 96, 1737- 1768.
- Crawford, V. P. and N. Iriberri (2007a): "Fatal attraction: Salience, naivete, and sophistication in experimental" hide-and-seek" games," American Economic Review, 97, 1731-1750.
- ---(2007b): "Level-k auctions: Can a nonequilibrium model of strategic thinking explain the winner's curse and overbidding in private-value auctions?" Econometrica, 75, 1721- 1770.
- Duffy, J., J. Ochs, and L. Vesterlund (2007): "Giving little by little: Dynamic voluntary contribution games," Journal of Public Economics, 91, 1708-1730.
- Eyster, E. and M. Rabin (2010): "Naive herding in rich-information settings," American economic journal: microeconomics, 2, 221-43.
- Fey, M., R. D. McKelvey, and T. R. Palfrey (1996): "An experimental study of constant-sum centipede games," International Journal of Game Theory, 25, 269-287.
- García-Pola, B., N. Iriberri, and J. Kovářík (2020a): "Hot versus cold behavior in centipede games," Journal of the Economic Science Association, 6, 226-238.
- ---(2020b): "Non-equilibrium play in centipede games," Games and Economic Behavior, 120, 391-433.
- Goeree, J. K., C. A. Holt, and T. R. Palfrey (2016): Quantal Response Equilibrium: A Stochastic Theory of Games, Princeton University Press.
- Hauser, D. N. and J. A. Bohren (2021): "Learning with Heterogeneous Misspecified Models: Characterization and Robustness," PIER Working Paper.
- Healy, P. J. (2017): "Epistemic experiments: Utilities, beliefs, and irrational play," .
- Ho, T.-H., C. Camerer, and K. Weigelt (1998): "Iterated dominance and iterated best response in experimental" p-beauty contests"," The American Economic Review, 88, 947-969.
- Ho, T.-H., S.-E. Park, and X. Su (2021): "A Bayesian Level-k Model in n-Person Games," Management Science, 67, 1622-1638.
- Ho, T.-H. and X. Su (2013): "A dynamic level-k model in sequential games," Management Science, 59, 452-469.
- Kawagoe, T. and H. Takizawa (2012): "Level-k analysis of experimental centipede games," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 82, 548-566.
- Kreps, D. M. and R. Wilson (1982): "Sequential Equilibria," Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 50, 863-894.
- Levitt, S. D., J. A. List, and S. E. Sadoff (2011): "Checkmate: Exploring backward induction among chess players," American Economic Review, 101, 975-90.
- Li, Z., P.-H. Lin, S.-Y. Kong, D. Wang, and J. Duffy (2021): "Conducting large, repeated, multi-game economic experiments using mobile platforms," PloS one, 16, e0250668.
- Marx, L. M. and S. A. Matthews (2000): "Dynamic voluntary contribution to a public project," The Review of Economic Studies, 67, 327-358.
- McKelvey, R. D. and R. G. Niemi (1978): "A multistage game representation of so- phisticated voting for binary procedures," Journal of Economic Theory, 18, 1-22.
- McKelvey, R. D. and T. R. Palfrey (1992): "An experimental study of the centipede game," Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 803-836.
- ---(1998): "Quantal response equilibria for extensive form games," Experimental eco- nomics, 1, 9-41.
- Megiddo, N. (1986): Remarks on bounded rationality, Citeseer.
- Milgrom, P. and J. Roberts (1982): "Limit pricing and entry under incomplete in- formation: An equilibrium analysis," Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 443-459.
- Nagel, R. (1995): "Unraveling in guessing games: An experimental study," The American Economic Review, 85, 1313-1326.
- Nagel, R. and F. F. Tang (1998): "Experimental results on the centipede game in normal form: an investigation on learning," Journal of Mathematical psychology, 42, 356-384.
- Palacios-Huerta, I. and O. Volij (2009): "Field centipedes," American Economic Review, 99, 1619-35.
- Rapoport, A., W. E. Stein, J. E. Parco, and T. E. Nicholas (2003): "Equilib- rium play and adaptive learning in a three-person centipede game," Games and Economic Behavior, 43, 239-265.
- Rosenthal, R. W. (1981): "Games of perfect information, predatory pricing and the chain-store paradox," Journal of Economic theory, 25, 92-100.
- Selten, R. (1978): "The chain store paradox," Theory and decision, 9, 127-159.
- ---(1991): "Anticipatory learning in two-person games," in Game equilibrium models I, Springer, 98-154.
- ---(1998): "Features of experimentally observed bounded rationality," European Eco- nomic Review, 42, 413-436.
- Stahl, D. O. (1993): "Evolution of smartn players," Games and Economic Behavior, 5, 604-617.
- ---(1996): "Boundedly rational rule learning in a guessing game," Games and Economic Behavior, 16, 303-330.
- Stahl, D. O. and P. W. Wilson (1995): "On players' models of other players: Theory and experimental evidence," Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 218-254.
- Wang, J. T.-Y., M. Spezio, and C. F. Camerer (2010): "Pinocchio's pupil: using eyetracking and pupil dilation to understand truth telling and deception in sender-receiver games," American Economic Review, 100, 984-1007.
- Zauner, K. G. (1999): "A payoff uncertainty explanation of results in experimental cen- tipede games," Games and Economic Behavior, 26, 157-185.