The aim of the paper is to extend the model of "fishing problem". The simple formulation is following. The angler goes to fishing. He buys fishing ticket for a fixed time. There are two places for fishing at the lake. The fishes are caught according to renewal processes which are different at both places. The fishes' weights and the inter-arrival times are given by the sequences of i.i.d. random variables with known distribution functions. These distributions are different for the first and second fishing place. The angler's satisfaction measure is given by difference between the utility function dependent on size of the caught fishes and the cost function connected with time. On each place the angler has another utility functions and another cost functions. In this way, the angler's relative opinion about these two places is modeled. For example, on the one place better sort of fish can be caught with bigger probability or one of the places is more comfortable...
FAQs
AI
What are the main components of the double optimal stopping problem in fishing models?add
The double optimal stopping problem involves the angler's choice of stopping times τ * 1 and τ * 2 to maximize expected satisfaction based on fishing claims and accumulated weights from two different locations.
How does the utility function differ across fishing locations in the model?add
The model incorporates distinct utility functions g_i and cost functions c_i for each of the two fishing places, reflecting the varying probabilities and comforts associated with fish catching.
What does the research suggest about optimal stopping times for maximum payoff?add
The findings indicate that optimal stopping times τ * 1 and τ * 2 can be determined through dynamic programming methods, achieving maximum expected satisfaction given a fixed time horizon.
How does the number of claims affect the stopping time strategies?add
The research distinguishes between fixed and infinite claims, showing that optimal stopping strategies change based on the density function characteristics and claims' limiting behavior.
What implications does the model have for practical fishing strategy optimizations?add
The analytical framework allows anglers to adaptively switch fishing spots to optimize their catch throughout a limited time, enhancing both strategy and expected gains.
Fishing provides an important part of the food for people in some developing countries. This can lead to a worrying cascade of overfishing, collapsing catches and rising market prices, and the extinction of many species. How can we prevent this situation from becoming catastrophic and, on the contrary, stabilize it? Mathematical modelling, by coupling ecological and economic dynamics, provides a better understanding of the dynamics of fisheries systems. It is presented here in a basic way and illustrated by the particular case of thiof, an emblematic species threatened in Senegal.
Canadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Sciences, 2000
Dynamic programming was used to model targeting decisions made by bottom trawling vessels in the U.S. west coast groundfish fishery, under management-imposed limits on landings of each target species (trip limits). A model of choice of assemblage (bottom rockfish (Sebastes sp.) versus deepwater Dover sole (Microstomus pacificus) complex) within a fishing trip was parameterized with data from an observer study conducted in 1988 through 1990. The model predicted that the vessel would fish the bottom rockfish strategy exclusively without limits but would switch between strategies several times under restrictive trip limits. That higher limits increased switching was consistent with actual landings from trips made by the same vessels under the same trip limit regimes, although the actual landings were more variable. Different trip limits or different market prices for the limited species changed the predicted decisions. Changing the cost of fishing each strategy, probability of a premature trip ending, tow duration, and time between tows also changed the predicted decisions, but the input parameters had to be well outside the range of values observed in the fishery.
The paper investigates an age-structured infinite-horizon optimal control model of harvesting a biological resource, interpreted as fish. Time and age are considered as continuum variables. The main result shows that in case of selective fishing, where only fish of prescribed sizes is harvested, it may be advantageous in the log run to implement a periodic fishing effort, rather than constant (the latter suggested by single-fish models that disregard the age-heterogeneity). Thus taking into account the age-structure of the fish may qualitatively change the theoretically optimal fishing mode. This result is obtained by developing a technique for reliable numerical verification of second order necessary optimality conditions for the considered problem. This technique could be useful for other optimal control problems of periodic age-structured systems.
We consider the problem of modelling uncertainty in the location of schools of fish and the effect of search by fishing vessels in reducing the uncertainty. Our methods involve a preliminary period of searching and fishing, followed by a Bayesian update of information and a reallocation of vessels. The first search problem that we study is how to determine the optimal allocation of search effort over several historical fishing grounds, in which the current abundance of fish has a known prior probability distribution. In our second application, we consider the case of a single fishing ground and determine the optimal allocation of search effort over time. We assume that fishermen are profit maximizers (although this can be relaxed) and compare the value of competitive fishing strategies with cooperative ones in which search effort is optimized.
The optimal harvesting time in a fish farm is analyzed in the paper. Fish population is assumed to be heterogeneous with respect to weight, so a distributed parameter dynamic model is considered. Theoretical and numerical results are obtained and compared with the ones concerning homogeneous fish cultures only. The results are applied to the tilapia farming in Mexico for which empirical and market data were obtained. The actual managerial practices turn out to be close to the optimal solution in the model where weight-heterogeneity of the culture is taken into account.
A two non-linear dynamic models, first one in two state variables and one control and the second one with three state variables and one control, are presented for the purpose of finding the optimal combination of exploitation, capital investment and price variation in the commercial fishing industry. This optimal combination is determined in terms of management policies. Exploitation, capital and price variation are controlled through the utilization rate of available capital. A novel feature in this model is that the variation of the capital depends on the income.
Because ofthe extreme uncertainty in fisheries biology, efforts to determine a stock-recruitment relationship have not been entirely successful. In the face of this uncertainty, this paper argues for a change in focus for fisheries economics from bioeconomic optimization toward goals which are more modest and more easily achievable. In particular, a satisficing approach to management is advocated, whereby efforts are made to reallocate some porportion of effort from overutilized to underutilized fisheries, with no attempt to determine the optimum. In order to achieve such a solution efficiently, managers must accurately predict the response of fishermen to public policy. This paper reports on a study which develops a discrete choice model to predict fishermen's supply response. Fishermen are shown to respond to economic incentives of expected returns and variability of returns, but only after these incentives surpass a substantial threshold. The Argument for Behavioral Modeling Uncertainty permeates the fishery management problem. This paper attempts to deal with the complexities arising from a num
Anna Karpowicz 12 and Krzysztof Szajowski 13 1 Institute of Mathematics and Computer Science Wrocław University of Technology Wybrzeże Wyspiańskiego 27 PL-50-370 Wrocław, Poland 2 (e-mail: anna.karpowicz@pwr.wroc.pl) 3 (e-mail: krzysztof.szajowski@pwr.wroc.pl)
Abstract
The aim of the paper is to extend the model of “fishing problem”. The simple formulation is following. The angler goes to fishing. He buys fishing ticket for a fixed time. There are two places for fishing at the lake. The fishes are caught according to renewal processes which are different at both places. The fishes’ weights and the inter-arrival times are given by the sequences of i.i.d. random variables with known distribution functions. These distributions are different for the first and second fishing place. The angler’s satisfaction measure is given by difference between the utility function dependent on size of the caught fishes and the cost function connected with time. On each place the angler has another utility functions and another cost functions. In this way, the angler’s relative opinion about these two places is modeled. For example, on the one place better sort of fish can be caught with bigger probability or one of the places is more comfortable. Obviously our angler wants to have as much satisfaction as possible and additionally he have to leave the lake before the fixed moment. Therefore his goal is to find two optimal stopping times in order to maximize his satisfaction. The first time corresponds to the moment, when he eventually should change the place and the second time, when he should stop fishing. These stopping times have to be less than the fixed time of fishing. The value of the problem and the optimal stopping times are derived.
The solution of double optimal stopping problem, in so called “fishing problem”, will be presented. One of the first author who considered the basic version of this problem was Starr (1974) and further generalizations were done by Starr and Woodroofe (1974), Starr, Wardrop, and Woodroofe (1976), Kramer and Starr (1990). The detailed review of the papers connected with “fishing problem” was presented by Ferguson (1997). The simple formulation of our double optimal stopping problem is following. The angler goes to fishing. He buys fishing ticket for a fixed time t0. There are two places for fishing at the lake and he can change the place at any moment s. The fishes
are caught according to renewal processes {Ni(t),t≥0}, where Ni(t) is the number of claims during the time t at the place i∈{1,2}. Let Ti,n denote the moment of n-th claim at the place i (we fix T1,0=0 and T2,0=s ), then the random variables Si,n=Ti,n−Ti,n−1 are i.i.d. with continuous distribution function (c.d.f. for short) Fi. The fishes’ weights, which were caught at the place i, are given by the sequence of i.i.d. random variables Xi,0,Xi,1,Xi,2,… with c.d.f. Hi (we fix X1,0=0 and X2,0=0 ). The renewal process is independent on the sequence of claims. The angler’s satisfaction measure is given by difference between the utility function gi:[0,∞)→[0,Gi] dependent on size of the caught fishes and the cost function ci:[0,t0]→[0,Ci] connected with time. We assume that gi and ci are continuous and bounded, additionally ci is differentiable. On each place the angler has different utility functions and cost functions. In this way, the angler’s relative opinion about these two places is modeled. For example, on the one position better sort of fish can be caught with bigger probability or one of the piers is more comfortable. The angler can change the place of fishing at any time s. The mass of the fishes Mts which were caught up to time t if the change of the position took place at the time s(Mt=Mtt) is given by
Mts=n=1∑Ni(s∧t)X1,n+n=1∑N2((t−s)+)X2,n
Let Z(s,t) denote the angler’s payoff for stopping at time t if the change of the position took place at time s. The payoff can be expressed as
Z(s,t)=⎩⎨⎧g1(Mt)−c1(t)g1(Ms)−c1(s)+g2(Mts−Ms)−c2(t−s)−C if t<s≤t0 if s≤t≤t0 if t0<t
where C=C1+C2. With the notation w2(m,s,m,t)=w1(m,s)+g2(m−m)−c2(t−s) and w1(m,t)=g1(m)−c1(t), formula (1) reduces to
Let Ft=σ(X1,0,T1,0,X1,1,T1,1,…,X1,N1(t),T1,N1(t)) be the σ-field generated by all events up to time t, if there was no change of parameters and Fs,t=σ(Fs,X2,0,T2,0,…,X2,N2(t−s),T2,N2(t−s)), the σ-field generated by all events up to time t if the change of parameters was at time s. For simplicity of notation we set Fn:=FT1,n,Fs,n:=Fs,T2,n. Let M(Fn) denote the set of non-negative and Fn-measurable random variables. From now on, T and Ts stands for the sets of stopping times with respect to the σ-fields {Ft,t≥0} and {Fs,t,0≤s≤t}, respectively. Furthermore, define for n∈N and n≤K the sets Tn,K={τ∈T:τ≥0,T1,n≤τ≤T1,K} and
Tn,Ks={τ∈Ts:0≤s≤τ,T2,n≤τ≤T2,K}. Obviously our angler wants to have as much satisfaction as possible and he has to leave the lake before the fixed moment. Therefore his goal is to find two stopping times τ1∗ and τ2∗ such that the expected gain is maximized
EZ(τ1∗,τ2∗)=τ1∈Tsupτ2∈Tτ1supEZ(τ1,τ2)
where τ1∗ corresponds to the moment, when he eventually should change the place and τ2∗, when he should stop fishing. These stopping times should be less than the fixed moment t0. The process Z(s,t) is piecewise-deterministic and belongs to the class of semi-Markov processes. The optimal stopping of similar processes was studied by Boshuizen and Gouweleeuw (1993). The special representation of stopping times from T and Ts is applied. It allows to use the dynamic programming methods to find these two optimal stopping times and to specify the expected satisfaction of the angler. The way of the solution is similar to the methods used by Karpowicz and Szajowski (2007). Let us first observe that by the properties of conditional expectation we have
Therefore in order to find τ1∗ and τ2∗, we have to calculate J(s) first. The process J(s) corresponds to the value of revenue function in the one stopping problem if the observation starts at the moment s.
3 Construction of the optimal second stopping time
In this section, we will find the solution of one stopping problem defined by (4). We will first solve the problem for fixed number of claims, next we will consider the case with infinite number of claims. In this section we fix s - the moment when the change took place and m=Ms - the mass of the fishes at the time s.
3.1 Fixed number of claims
In this subsection we are looking for optimal stopping time τ2,0,K∗:=τ2,K∗ such that
for n=K,…,1,0 and observe that ΓK,Ks=Z(s,T2,K). The crucial role in our subsequent considerations plays the following lemma (see Brémaud (1981)).
Lemma 1. If τ1∈T,τ2∈Ts, then there exist R1,n∈M(Fn) and R2,n∈M(Fs,n) respectively, such that τi∧Ti,n+1=(Ti,n+Ri,n)∧Ti,n+1 on {ω:τi(ω)≥Ti,n(ω)},i∈{1,2}, a.s.
Now we can derive the dynamic programming equations satisfied by Γn,Ks. To simplify notation we write Mt=Mts for t≤s,Mn=MT1,n,Mns=MT2,ns and Fˉi=1−Fi.
Theorem 1. Let s≥0 and ΓK,Ks=Z(s,T2,K). For n=K−1,K−2,…,0 we have
where ϑn,K(m,s,m,t,r)=I{t≤t0}{Fˉ2(r)[I{r≤t0−t}w2(m,s,m,t+r)−CI{r>t0−t}]+E[I{S2,n+1≤r}Γn+1,Ks[Fs,n]}−CI{t>t0}
It can be shown that there exists R2,ns such that Γn,Ks=ϑn,K(Ms,s,Mns,T2,n,R2,ns) for n≤K−1.
Theorem 2. Let R2,is be the sequence of Fs,i-measurable random variables (fix R2,Ks=0 ) and ηn,Ks=K∧inf{i≥n:R2,is<S2,i+1},n=0,…,K. Then Γn,Ks=E[Z(s,τ2,n,Ks)∣Fs,n], where τ2,n,Ks=T2,ηn,Ks+R2,ηn,Kss.
Lemma 2. Γn,Ks=γK−ns,Ms(Mns,T2,n) for n=K,…,0, where the sequence of functions γjs,m is given recursively as follows:
where κ2,δ(m,s,m,t,r)=Fˉ2(r)[I{r≤t0−t}w2(m,s,m,t+r)−CI{r>t0−t}]+∫0rdF2(z)∫0∞δ(m+x,t+z)dH2(x).
Let us denote αi=fi/Fˉi and let us set Δi(a)=E[gi(a+Xi)−gi(a)]. The sequence of functions γjs,m can be expressed as follows
where y2,j(a,b,c) is given recursively as follows y2,0(a,b,c)=0 and y2,j(a,b,c)=max0≤r≤cϕ2,y2,j−1(a,b,c,r) ϕ2,δ(a,b,c,r)=∫0rFˉ2(z){α2(z)[Δ2(a)+Eδ(a+X2,b+z,c−z)]−c2′(b+z)}dz.
The second optimal stopping time is constructed similarly like in Ferenstein and Sierociński (1997). Let B=B([0,∞)×[0,t0]×[0,t0]) be the space of all bounded, continuous functions with the norm ∥δ∥=supa,b,c∣δ(a,b,c)∣. It is complete space. Let us define the operator Φ2:B→B as
(Φ2δ)(a,b,c)=0≤r≤cmaxϕ2,δ(a,b,c,r)
We have y2,j(a,b,c)=(Φ2y2,j−1)(a,b,c) and by (8) there exists a function r2,j∗(a,b,c) such that y2,j(a,b,c)=ϕ2,y2,j−1(a,b,c,r2,j∗(a,b,c)) and γjs,m(m,t)=I{t≤t0}{w2(m,s,m,t)+ϕ2,y2,j−1(m−m,t−s,t0−t,r2,j∗(m−m,t−s,t0−t))}−CI{t>t0}. The consequence of the foregoing considerations is the optimal stopping times τ2,n,K∗ in following form:
Theorem 3. Let R2,i∗=r2,K−i∗(Mi∗−Ms,T2,i−s,t0−T2,i) for i=0,1,…,K moreover ηn,K∗=K∧inf{i≥n:R2,i∗<S2,i+1}, then the stopping time τ2,n,K∗=T2,ηn,K∗∗+R2,ηn,K∗∗ is optimal in the class Tn,K∗ and Γn,K∗=E[Z(s,τ2,n,K∗)∣Fs,n].
3.2 Infinite number of claims
The solution of one stopping problem, related to construction of the second stopping moment, for infinite number of claims is obtained under assumption that F2(t0)<1. If F2(t0)<1 then the operator Φ2:B→B defined by (9) is a contraction. By (8) and the contraction properties we get by fixed point theorem that there exists y2∈B such that y2=Φ2y2 and limK→∞∥y2,K−y2∥=0. It implies that y2 is measurable and γs,m=limK→∞γKs,m is given by
We can now calculate the optimal strategy and the expected gain after changing place.
Theorem 4. If F2(t0)<1 and has the density function f2, then
(i) for n∈N the limit τ2,n∗=limK→∞τ2,n,K∗ a.s. exists and τ2,n∗≤t0 is an optimal stopping rule in the set T∗∩{τ≥T2,n},
(ii) E[Z(s,τ2,n∗)∣Fs,n]=γs,m(Mn∗,T2,n) a.s.
It can be proved that the function γs,m(m,s) with respect to s is left-hand differentiable. It allows to construct the optimal the first optimal stopping moment similarly as the second one. To this end we have to take as the payoff function γs,m(m,s)=I{s≤t0}u(m,s)−CI{s>t0}, where u(m,s)=g1(m)−c1(s)+g2(0)−c2(0)+g˙2(t0−s) is continuous, bounded, measurable with bounded left-hand derivatives with respect to s. The conditional value function of the second optimal stopping problem has the form:
J(s)=E[Z(s,τ2∗)∣Fs]=γs,Ms(Ms,s) a.s.
The first optimal stopping moment in the considered problem is equal τ1∗ such that J(τ1∗)=supτ∈TEJ(τ).
Example 1. If S2 has exponential distribution with constant hazard rate α2,g2 is increasing and concave, c2 is convex and t2,n=T2,n,mns=Mns then
where s is the moment of changing place. Moreover if S1 has exponential distribution with constant hazard rate α1,g1 is increasing and concave, c1 is convex and t1,n=T1,n,mn=Mn then
If for i=1 and i=2 the functions gi are increasing and convex, ci are concave and Si have exponential distribution with constant hazard rate αi then τ1,ns=τ2,ns=t0 for n∈N.
4 Conclusions
This article presents the solution of double stopping problem in “fishing model” for finite horizon. The analytical properties of the reward function in one stopping problem played the crucial rule in our considerations and allowed us to extend the problem to double stopping. It is easy to generalize our model and the solution to multiple stopping problem.
Bibliography
Boshuizen, F., Gouweleeuw, J., 1993. General optimal stopping theorems for semi-Markov processes. Adv. in Appl. Probab. 4, 825-846.
Brémaud, P., 1981. Point Processes and Queues. Martingale Dynamics. Springer-Verlag, New York.
Ferenstein, E., Sierociński, A., 1997. Optimal stopping of a risk process. Applicationes Mathematicae 24(3), 335-342.
Ferguson, T., 1997. A Poisson fishing model. In: Pollard, D., Torgersen, E., Yang, G. (Eds.), Festschrift for Lucien Le Cam: Research Papers in Probability and Statistics. Springer, New York, pp. 234-244.
Karpowicz, A., Szajowski, K., 2007. Double optimal stopping of a risk process. Stochastics: An International Journal of Probability and Stochastic Processes 79,155−167.
Kramer, M., Starr, N., 1990. Optimal stopping in a size dependent search. Sequential Anal. 9, 59-80.
Starr, N., 1974. Optimal and adaptive stopping based on capture times. J. Appl. Prob. 11, 294 - 301.
Starr, N., Wardrop, R., Woodroofe, M., 1976. Estimating a mean from delayed observations. Z. für Wahr. 35, 103-113.
Starr, N., Woodroofe, M., 1974. Gone fishin’: Optimal stopping based on catch times. Tech. Rep. 33, University of Michigan, Dept. of Statistics.
References (9)
Boshuizen, F., Gouweleeuw, J., 1993. General optimal stopping theorems for semi-Markov processes. Adv. in Appl. Probab. 4, 825-846.
Brémaud, P., 1981. Point Processes and Queues. Martingale Dynamics. Springer-Verlag, New York.
Ferenstein, E., Sierociński, A., 1997. Optimal stopping of a risk process. Appli- cationes Mathematicae 24(3), 335-342.
Ferguson, T., 1997. A Poisson fishing model. In: Pollard, D., Torgersen, E., Yang, G. (Eds.), Festschrift for Lucien Le Cam: Research Papers in Proba- bility and Statistics. Springer, New York, pp. 234-244.
Karpowicz, A., Szajowski, K., 2007. Double optimal stopping of a risk process. Stochastics: An International Journal of Probability and Stochastic Processes 79, 155-167.
Kramer, M., Starr, N., 1990. Optimal stopping in a size dependent search. Sequential Anal. 9, 59-80.
Starr, N., 1974. Optimal and adaptive stopping based on capture times. J. Appl. Prob. 11, 294 -301.
Starr, N., Wardrop, R., Woodroofe, M., 1976. Estimating a mean from delayed observations. Z. für Wahr. 35, 103-113.
Starr, N., Woodroofe, M., 1974. Gone fishin': Optimal stopping based on catch times. Tech. Rep. 33, University of Michigan, Dept. of Statistics.
In this paper we consider the following problem. An angler buys a fishing ticket that allows him/her to fish for a fixed time. There are two locations to fish at the lake. The fish are caught according to a renewal process, which is different for each fishing location. The angler's success is defined as the difference between the utility function, which is dependent on the size of the fish caught, and the time-dependent cost function. These functions are different for each fishing location. The goal of the angler is to find two optimal stopping times that maximize his/her success: when to change fishing location and when to stop fishing. Dynamic programming methods are used to find these two optimal stopping times and to specify the expected success of the angler at these times.
In this work we study a structured fishing model, basically displaying the two stages of the ages of a fish population, which are in our case juvenile, and adults. We associate to this model the maximization of the total discounted net revenues derived by the exploitation of the stock. The exploitation strategy of the optimal control problem is then developed and presented. To cite this article: M. Jerry, N. Raïssi, C. R. Biologies 328 (2005). 2004 Académie des sciences. Published by Elsevier SAS. All rights reserved. Résumé Stratégie optimale d'un problème de pêche basé sur un modèle structuré. Ce travail consiste en l'étude d'un modèle structuré mettant en évidence les différents stades d'âge du stock, en l'occurrence juvénile et adulte. Nous associons à ce modèle la maximisation du total escompté du revenu net généré par l'exploitation du stock. La stratégie d'exploitation du problème de contrôle optimal est recherché. Pour citer cet article : M. Jerry, N. Raïssi, C. R. Biologies 328 (2005).
In this paper a bioeconomic model is developed for a commercial fishery with multiple gear types in the case of two independent fish species. Where most bioeconomic fishery models focus on either multiple gear types or multiple species (mostly predator-prey relationships) this model combines both aspects for four gear types and two independent fish species. The objective of the paper is to find the optimal allocation of four gear types per period to obtain the highest net benefits while harvesting at a sustainable rate. This is done by developing a discrete time LP-model for a sole owner fishery, given a Total Allowable Catch for the two fish species. The model is applied to the Chippewas of Nawash First Nation commercial fishery in Lake Huron and Georgian Bay (Ontario, Canada). Sensitivity analyses are performed on price changes as well as on the average harvest levels per boat.
We study the growth of populations in a random environment subjected to variable effort fishing policies. The models used are stochastic differential equations and the environmental fluctuations may either affect an intrinsic growth parameter or be of the additive noise type. Density-dependent natural growth and fishing policies are of very general form so that our results will be model independent. We obtain conditions on the fishing policies for non-extinction and for non-fixation at the carrying capacity that are very similar to the conditions obtained for the corresponding deterministic model. We also obtain conditions for the existence of stationary distributions (as well as expressions for such distributions) very similar to conditions for the existence of an equilibrium in the corresponding deterministic model. The results obtained provide minimal requirements for the choice of a wise density-dependent fishing policy.
This work examines aquaculture-related activities in the commercial exploitation of fish reproduction. Fisheries' problem of maximizing utility is modeled for the state of Puebla, Mexico, to determine optimal fish production. The problem of maximizing utility subject to the fish production function is solved using an approach based on Euler's equation. The theoretical results are then applied, using data on aquaculture production and tilapia sales prices in the state of Puebla, Mexico. A logarithmic regression is used to approximate the utility function. The optimal fishing production and utility functions are thus explicitly obtained. Furthermore, this work shows how to obtain greater profits from the amount of fish that can be extracted without reducing the fish population.
Many mathematical models use functions the value of which cannot exceed some physically or biologically imposed maximum value. A model can be described as 'capped-rate' when the rate of change of a variable cannot exceed a maximum value. This presents no problem when the models are deterministic but, in many applications, results from deterministic models are at best misleading. The need to account for stochasticity, both demographic and environmental, in models is therefore important but, as this paper shows, incorporating stochasticity into capped-rate models is not trivial. A method using queueing theory is presented, which allows randomness and spatial heterogeneity to be incorporated rigorously into capped rate models. The method is applied to the feeding and growth of fish larvae.
Considerable attention has been given in the literature recently to continuous time dy namic maximizing models for fisheries in general, but the time discreteness and inter dependency problems encountered in the case of most salmon fisheries have been largely ignored. Hence, a discrete time profit maximizing model for a salmon fishery is devel oped in this paper, and it is shown that a correct salmon management policy takes the form of an investment decision with respect to the level of escapempnt and that a man agement policy of maximum sustained yield may be incorrect from an economic stand point. It is hoped that continued research including construction of a working model will provide some indication of the difference between the magnitude of spawner stocks se lected on the basis of maximum sustained yield and stocks selected on the basis of economic optimality. Continuous time dynamic maximIzmg models have been developed in the literature recently to handle the problem of...
An age structured model of a fishery is studied where two fishing fleets, or fishing agents, are targeting two different mature age classes of the fish stock. The agents are using different fishing gear with different fishing selectivity. The model includes young and old mature fish that can be harvested, in addition to an age class of immature fish. The paper describes the optimal harvesting policy under different assumptions on the objectives of the social planner and on fishing selectivity. First, biomass yield is maximized under perfect fishing selectivity, second, equilibrium profit (rent) is maximized under perfect fishing selectivity, and third, equilibrium profit is maximized under imperfect fishing selectivity. The paper provides results that differ significantly from the standard lumped parameter (also surplus production, or biomass) model.
Journal of Economics, Business and Management, 2017
The present work joins in a scientific context which returns within the framework of the modelling and of the mathematical and IT analysis of models in dynamics of populations. In particular, it deals with the application of the mathematics and with the computing in the management of fisheries. In this work, we define a bio-economic model in the case of two marine species whose natural growth is modeled by a logistic law. These two marine species are exploited by two fishermen. The objective of the work is to find the fishing effort that maximizes the profit of each fisherman by using Nash equilibrium and taking into account constraints related to the conservation of biodiversity.
ICES Journal of Marine Science: Journal du Conseil, 2015
Developing bioeconomic models of sequential fisheries is complicated when the two (or more) fisheries overlap temporally. In such cases, each fishery will be affected by the other, so both cannot be properly modelled as separate activities. This has recently become an issue for the Northern Prawn Fishery, in which bioeconomic modelling is used to set management limits. Modelling has focused on the tiger prawn component of the fishery, which mostly occurs in the second half of the year. However, successful management leading to stock recovery has resulted in this fishery now overlapping temporally with the banana prawn fishery, which occurs in the first half of the year. Ideally, an integrated model covering the whole year would be developed, but this is not practical for a number of reasons. In this study, we model the factors driving the level of fishing effort in the banana prawn fishery, which affects, and is affected by, the tiger prawn fishery. As expected, banana prawn fishing effort is driven largely by stock size, fleet size, catch rates, prices, and fuel costs. Effort increases with fleet size, but at a decreasing rate. Further, we find evidence that opportunity cost, namely the ability to fish in the tiger prawn fishery and the price of tiger prawns, also affects the level of effort in the banana prawn fishery.